Skip to main content
Jean Monnet Chair on EU Approach to Better Regulation
Search
Navigazione principale
About the Chair
Mission
Chair holder
Key staff
Network
Submissions
Contact us
Teaching activities
Amministrazione e qualità della regolazione
Better Regulation - EMLE / LEARI
Diritto amministrativo
Alta formazione professionale qualità regolazione (Archive)
Short course on regulation (Archive)
EU Approach to Better Regulation (Archive)
Testimonials
Chair’s Outreach
Chair’s Events
Contest buona pratica regolatoria
Newsletter
Internships
RegWorld
Main events
Publications
Documents
Literature
Conferences
Navigazione principale
About the Chair
Mission
Chair holder
Key staff
Network
Submissions
Contact us
Teaching activities
Amministrazione e qualità della regolazione
Better Regulation - EMLE / LEARI
Diritto amministrativo
Alta formazione professionale qualità regolazione (Archive)
Short course on regulation (Archive)
EU Approach to Better Regulation (Archive)
Testimonials
Chair’s Outreach
Chair’s Events
Contest buona pratica regolatoria
Newsletter
Internships
RegWorld
Main events
Publications
Documents
Literature
Conferences
Jean Monnet Chair on EU Approach to Better Regulation
Search
Breadcrumb
Home
Publications
Publications
Title
Author
Category
- Any -
Documents
Literature
SubCategory
- Any -
Artificial Intelligence and new technologies regulation
Behavioural regulation
Better Regulation
Blockchain and cryptocurrencies regulation
Climate-related regulation
Clinical education
Competition advocacy
Competition enforcement
Consultations and Stakeholders inclusion tools
Corruption prevention
Cost-benefit analysis
Digital markets
Drafting
Environmental regulation
Ex post evaluation
Experimental approach to law and regulation
Food safety regulation
Impact assessment
Independent authorities
International regulatory co-operation
International Organisations and Networks: selected documents
Lobbying
Participative and deliberative democracy
Public utilities
Rassegna Trimestrale Osservatorio AIR
Regulation and Covid-19
Regulatory and Administrative Burdens Measurement
Regulatory enforcement
Regulatory governance
Regulatory reforms
Regulatory sandboxes
Risk-based regulation
Rulemaking
Simplification
Soft regulation
Transparency
Year
Literature
Regulatory and Administrative Burdens Measurement
Helm D. (2006)
Regulatory reform, capture, and the regulatory burden
This paper provides a critique of broad aggregate proposals to reduce the regulatory burden. It argues that the public debate about regulatory reform and red tape is loose and general, with little regard for the complex ways in which regulation imposes costs and benefits on the economy. Although there are theoretical reasons to expect regulation to be in excess supply, there is little empirical analysis to link aggregate regulation with productivity and economic growth. Regulation is itself a public good, and many aspects of economic efficiency require regulation to address market failures. The main efficiency issues are better addressed through a disaggregated approach, focusing on when, where, and how to regulate, rather than on crude aggregate estimates of the total burden. The design of regulation needs to take account of regulatory capture, and it is argued that market-based instruments and independent regulatory bodies tend to reduce the scope for capture. The incentives and employment rules governing regulatory institutions are also discussed. In ignoring these disaggregated regulatory design problems, crude aggregate targets for the reduction of regulation, and rules such as ‘one in, one out’ may be counter-productive.
Literature
Drafting
Tanner E. (2006)
Clear, Simple, and Precise Legislative Drafting: How Does a European Community Directive Fare?
In 2001, Martin Cutts redrafted Toy-Safety Directive 88/378/EEC in plain language. He criticized the language of that Directive as being archaic legalese. He added that Directives, as a whole, were poorly drafted. The European Commissions Legal Service rejected his criticisms. It stated that it had published the European Commission's plain language guidelines after Directive 88/378/EEC had been drafted. In a previous article in the Statute Law Review, Butt and Castle's plain language guidelines were explicated using examples from Directive 2002/2/EC. In this article, their guidelines are applied to the whole of that Directive to see if its language is 'clear, simple, and precise'. The criticisms made in the previous article, combined with those made in this article, suggest that the drafters of Directive 2002/2/EC have not yet mastered the skill of writing in 'clear, simple, and precise' language
Documents
Simplification
OECD (2006)
Cutting Red Tape: National Strategies for Administrative Simplification
Most OECD countries have made policies to reduce administrative burdens – cutting red tape – a political priority. Red tape is particularly burdensome to smaller companies and may inhibit entrepreneurship. These effects are more costly in global markets, where competitiveness can be affected by the efficiency of the domestic regulatory and administrative environment. But citizens and large firms also complain about unnecessary reporting requirements. Results are wanted.
What can governments do? Strategies include setting quantitative targets to reduce administrative burdens when new regulations are drafted and by reviewing older regulations; codification; better multi-level co-ordination; and rapid introduction of e-government services. Supported by taskforces and advisory committees, governments increasingly locate responsibility in a central administrative unit. This “whole-of-government” approach represents a major step in recent years, embedding administrative simplification in the overall regulatory quality system at the national level.
Literature
Better Regulation
Baldwin R. (2005)
Is better regulation smarter regulation?
The quest for “better” regulation is one being driven forward with a new urgency within the United Kingdom, the European Union and by international bodies such as the OECD. In this country,
regulatory improvement strategies have been applied by governments for nearly 20 years and it is now appropriate to consider whether the better regulation movement is founded on secure approaches and assumptions; whether it is heading in the right conceptual direction, and, more particularly, whether it conduces to “smarter” regulatory regimes--regimes that offer the best mixtures of regulatory instruments and institutions.
This article outlines the development of the better regulation movement within government, it describes the regulatory improvement tools that governments have deployed in furthering that movement, and then it considers the capacity of the “better regulation” approach to deliver smarter regulation. It will be argued that there are a number of identifiable reasons--practical and theoretical--why the better regulation movement may not readily conduce to the production of “smarter” regulatory policies and regimes.
Literature
Impact assessment
Radaelli C. (2005)
What Does Regulatory Impact Assessment Mean in Europe?
Regulatory Impact Analysis (RIA) has emerged on the European political agenda. It is an idea whose time has come. Both the member states and the institutions of the European Union (EU) are presently investing in programmes for ‘better regulation’ and ‘good regulatory governance’. RIA is the cornerstone of these programmes. This paper explains how RIA is being diffused in Europe. Is the introduction of RIA in Europe simply the diffusion of an idea, the content of which remains very different in the various national contexts? Or, alternatively, has the diffusion of ideas brought about convergence at the level of how RIA is performed? As shown by Hahn and Litan (2004), European impact assessments are often different from North-American RIAs. This paper shows that the adoption of a common RIA ‘bottle’ has not produced similar European ‘wines’. The language of RIA has produced a community of discourse for policy-makers and has stimulated the introduction of some instruments that are similarly labelled ‘impact assessment’. But RIA practice may exist only on paper, and in some cases the ‘RIA label’ may reveal basic assessments of administrative burdens. The paper explains how ideas can be diffused without convergence of results. The argument here is not the trivial one that ‘context matters’, but how it matters. Hence the paper breaks down ‘context’ into four dimensions, that is, institutions, models of the policy process, actors, and legitimacy. Institutional design, the capacity to deal with distributional problems, heterogeneity in multi-level governance systems, policy styles, and the ‘weights’ given to the preferences of different RIA actors explain the lack of convergence.
Literature
Experimental approach to law and regulation
Guala F. (2005)
The Methodology of Experimental Economics
The experimental approach in economics is a driving force behind some of the most exciting developments in the field. The 'experimental revolution' was based on a series of bold philosophical premises which have remained until now mostly unexplored. This book provides the first comprehensive analysis and critical discussion of the methodology of experimental economics, written by a philosopher of science with expertise in the field. It outlines the fundamental principles of experimental inference in order to investigate their power, scope and limitations. The author demonstrates that experimental economists have a lot to gain by discussing openly the philosophical principles that guide their work, and that philosophers of science have a lot to learn from their ingenious techniques devised by experimenters in order to tackle difficult scientific problems.
Documents
Regulatory and Administrative Burdens Measurement
HMT (2005)
Hampton Review on Reducing Administrative Burdens
Documents
Better Regulation
BRTF (Better Regulation Task Force) (2005)
Regulation - Less is More: Reducing Burdens, Improving Outcomes
Documents
Regulatory and Administrative Burdens Measurement
European Commission (2005)
Better regulation for Growth and Jobs in the European Union, Minimizing Administrative Costs imposed by Legislation, detailed outline of a possible EU Net Administrative Cost Model
Documents
Better Regulation
European Commission (2005)
Better regulation for Growth and Jobs in the European Union
Documents
Regulatory governance
OECD (2005)
OECD Guiding Principles for Regulatory Quality and Performance
Literature
Impact assessment
Radaelli C. (2004)
The diffusion of regulatory impact analysis – Best practice or lesson‐drawing?
This article presents the main results of a research project on regulatory impact analysis (RIA) in comparative perspective. Its main theoretical thrust is to explore the limitations of the conventional analysis of RIA in terms of de‐contextualised best practice and provide an alternative framework based on the lesson‐drawing literature. After having discussed how demand and supply of best practice emerge in the OECD and the European Union, some analytic (as opposed to normative) lessons are presented. The main lessons revolve around the politics of problem definition, the nesting of RIA into wider reform programmes, the political malleability of RIA, the trade‐off between precision and administrative assimilation, the roles of networks and watchdogs, and institutional learning. The conclusions discuss the implications of the findings for future research.
Literature
Behavioural regulation
Korobkin R. (2003)
Bounded Rationality, Standard Form Contracts, and Unconscionability
Economic theory suggests that, in most circumstances, market forces will ensure that standard form contracts contain terms that are not only socially efficient but also beneficial to non-drafting parties as a class compared to other possible combinations of price and terms. This analysis in turn suggests that courts should enforce all form terms or, at a minimum, all form terms that non-drafting parties read and understand. Relying on social science research on decisionmaking, this Article argues that non-drafting parties (usually buyers) are boundedly rational decisionmakers who will normally price only a limited number of product attributes as part of their purchase decision. When contract terms are not among these attributes, drafting parties will have a market incentive to include terms in their standard forms that favor themselves, whether or not such terms are efficient. Thus, there is no a priori reason to assume form contract terms will be efficient. The Article then argues that the proper policy response to this conclusion is greater use of mandatory contract terms and judicial modification of the unconscionability doctrine to better respond to the primary cause of contractual inefficiency.
Literature
Behavioural regulation
Thaler R. H., Sunstein C. R. (2003)
Libertarian Paternalism Is Not an Oxymoron
Literature
Better Regulation
Bardach R., Kagan R. (2003)
Going by the Book: The Problem of Regulatory Unreasonableness
Pagination
Previous page
‹‹
Page 36
Next page
››